Register For Our Mailing List

Register to receive our free weekly newsletter including editorials.

Home / 617

The rubbery numbers behind super tax concessions

As the proposed new Division 296 superannuation tax continues to be debated, Treasury’s Tax Expenditures and Insights Statement (TEIS), often enters the conversation. It quotes a total super tax concessions figure in the vicinity of $50 billion annually, a misleading figure that the proposed new super tax relies heavily upon for justification.

Misleading in the sense that it is based on an inappropriate benchmark for cost purposes, comparing the 15% tax on super contributions and earnings to what would have otherwise been collected if the individual’s marginal tax rate had applied.

The problem with this approach is that it ignores restrictions on access to super savings until retirement age, and that there is a compulsory element to contributions. This reduces the real value of super savings compared to funds readily available today. A more realistic attempt at calculating the tax concessions would apply a liquidity discount to account for inaccessibility. Treasury’s report also ignores behavioural changes in the absence of tax concessions.

In assuming super tax concessions are immediate give aways, the TEIS overlooks the real economic costs to individuals of tying up funds for decades. Calculating a liquidity cost to future savings would yield a more accurate assessment of any tax concessions. So what might a liquidity discount look like, and how would it be applied?

Quoting David Laibson in The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No.2 (1997): “Individuals often require more than a doubling or tripling of current consumption to defer gratification for a few decades.” Noting that behavioural experiments typically use nominal dollars, without reference to inflation, as people don’t generally adjust for that mentally.

And if deferring consumption was compulsory, you could argue for a multiple greater than two to three times. 

An example

So let’s assume someone might be indifferent to having $100 today or $300 in 30 years’ time. 

Implying that for any investment inaccessible for 30 years, the individual would value the expected maturity value at one-third of that amount, in today’s terms. Which represents a 66.7% discount on the future value, or annually, a liquidity discount rate of 3.73%. 

Even though an investment is expected to grow to a certain dollar value, the individual perceives it as worth only one-third of that because they can’t access it for 30 years. That is a loss of value in utility terms, not in nominal dollars.

If however, no restrictions applied to accessing funds over the 30 year period, then a liquidity discount would not apply, and the individual would value the investment at its full expected future value. 

Note that liquidity discounting is independent of investment performance. Rather, it is about how much a person devalues locked up money because they are unable to draw on it if needed, reallocate it if a better opportunity arises, or smooth consumption over time. In other words, the kind of behaviour the TEIS overlooks when it treats concessional tax rates as benefits without recognising the cost of loss of liquidity.  

In reality, an individual’s annual liquidity discount rate would decrease as time to accessibility of funds approaches. For example, a 35-year-old would value $100 available in 25 years’ time, less than a 55-year-old would value it in five years from now. The annual cost of foregone consumption or opportunity shrinks with time to access. And the decline in discount rate would not be linear, with a steadier drop from younger ages when there is a higher premium on liquidity and more uncertainty, to an accelerating decline as retirement approaches and the discount rate approaches zero.

The result being a curve with a non-linear concave decline as time to access approaches zero. Beginning with a maximum annual liquidity discount rate of 3.73%, such a curve might look like this:

This curve can be used to discount a stream of super fund contributions for illiquidity.   

For example, suppose $100 per year goes into a super account for 30 years earning 5% p.a. before tax. That is, $85 per year earning 4.25% after 15% tax, would accumulate to $5,183.

Applying the discount curve to this fund reduces the accumulated value to $3,567. That is, for this individual, the accumulated value of $5,183 in 30 years would be equivalent to $3,567 in today’s terms. This represents an overall discount for illiquidity of 31.2%, which would seem intuitively modest when forgoing access to funds for a full 30 years.

By comparison, assume the same contributions went into an ordinary taxed fund with no access restrictions, and a 30% marginal tax rate. Then $70 per year earning 3.5% after tax would accumulate to $3,740. Which is more than the super fund’s discounted value of $3,567. 

If, however, the super fund tax rate was lowered to 12.6%, then its accumulated value adjusted for illiquidity would be equal to the ordinary taxed fund’s value. 

That is, a fund with full access taxed at 30% accumulates to $3,740. A fund locked up and taxed at 12.6%, and allowing for illiquidity accumulates to $3,740. So a drop in tax rate from 30% to 12.6% is needed to compensate this individual for locking up his funds for 30 years.

But this individual would be paying 15% tax, so clearly there are no tax concessions for him. Yet the TEIS implies that he is the recipient of concessions because of benchmarking to his 30% marginal tax rate.

Going through the same process with a 37% marginal tax rate would yield a required super tax rate of 20.9% to compensate the investor for illiquidity. In that instance there would be small tax concessions when comparing to a tax rate of 15%. 

And a 45% marginal rate translates to a required 30.5% super tax rate. Again, concessions exist, but certainly not to the extent of the 15% super tax rate being assessed against 45%.

And if the same analysis is undertaken for a 40-year scenario, the following results are obtained:

Marginal tax rate | Super tax rate required
30% | 5.6%
37% | 14.3%
45% | 24.3%

That is, even less tax concessions, which makes intuitive sense when funds are locked up for an extra ten years.

Note that this analysis is based on a specific discount rate curve for illiquidity, the rate and shape of which can vary depending on individual circumstances like age, income level, family status, and so on. Even though there is no widely agreed discount rate size or profile, it could be estimated for example, by comparing returns between liquid and illiquid assets. Or it could be based on choice experiments that reveal results like an indifference between having something now, or a multiple of that in decades time. It could also be based on opportunity costs where individuals forgo access to funds, but have mortgage and/or credit card debt.

The need for an honest assessment

Suffice to say that illiquidity costs are real and discount rates will not be zero. While there may be a budgetary cost to running a superannuation system, there is also a personal economic cost, because locking up money long term is not free, and the assumption of a 0% liquidity premium in the TEIS is unrealistic. It is difficult to estimate without data, but modest discounting might as much as halve the value of super tax concessions reported.

If government is going to motivate people to save for retirement, it must be prepared to offer meaningful incentives to individuals for giving up access to large sums of money for many years. A reduced tax rate is one way, with the amount of reduction debatable. And if Treasury is going to introduce measures to help sway the debate, surely it has a duty to estimate those measures as accurately as possible.

 

Tony Dillon is a freelance writer and former actuary.

 

36 Comments
Dudley
June 27, 2025

"couple earning $60k outside super pay no tax":

. Annual salary: $0
. Spouse (married or de-facto), Spouse's annual income: $31,002
. Senior & pensioner offset (SAPTO)
. Deductions & Other Income, Dividends & Other income: $31,002
https://paycalculator.com.au/
.Tax: $0.00

John mussawir
June 27, 2025

If only it were a level playing field as some judges and pollies are not having applied to their super, why would they bother blocking it.

James#
June 27, 2025

@Franco: "Firstly George , non concessional contributions are very often after a CG event where the max tax rate is less than 25% of the gain"

Rubbish! I, like many others no doubt, have made NCC (under the rules and actually encouraged by government!) after having paid a 47% marginal tax rate on those dollars contributed! Not from some CG windfall! What percentage of these NCC's are from CG windfalls Franco? Easy to make groundless assertions in support of your gripe!

Michael
June 27, 2025

What everyone is missing is that s elf funded retirees also do not receive a pension and numerous other benefits linked to the pension.
How much effective taxation equivalent is that?

Dudley
June 27, 2025

"8% growth on $6mill( 480K)- 5% drawdown(300K) -3% inflation(180K) so the couple still have about $6 mill":

Or 16% growth, or 4%.

Still lose capital to inflation 'stealth tax' on super capital.

Couple can withdraw whatever from super to personal accounts, no tax, no change in capital.

Still lose same amount of capital to inflation 'stealth tax' on total of super and personal capital.

Couple can spend whatever from personal accounts, $0.01 to 2 * $3,000,000, reducing capital.

Still lose capital at same proportional rate to inflation 'stealth tax' on remaining super and personal capital.

No inflation 'stealth tax' concession.

James#
June 27, 2025

Dudley, you are indeed correct about the insidious 'stealth tax'. However getting government or Treasury, for that matter to acknowledge it, and factor it into their calculations/considerations isn't going to happen. Even more revenue would disappear if they did! With little appetite for spending restraint, fat chance of real productivity improvement (over regulation, unions & Labor industrial relations policies) and even less chance growing the economic pie (losing remaining industry to high energy costs & a shallow economy), only more needed revenue through higher taxes seems to be on the horizon.

Cfp
June 27, 2025

If you ask me many of these very large balances will not have death tax implications as they were put into super under old rules as undeducted contributions tax free, continue to enjoy tax free growth in pension accounts and will go to estate beneficiaries tax free. These super large accounts are Estate Planning vehicles and should definite be paying some form of taxation on earnings and ongoing growth. These super large owners of these huge amounts of capital can certainly afford it.

GeorgeB
June 27, 2025

“very large balances …were put into super ..as undeducted contributions tax free”

As noted elsewhere in the comments undeducted or concessional contributions are not taxed going in because they have already been taxed as income, meaning (for higher income earners) that about $1 income tax was paid for every $1 contributed.

“continue to enjoy tax free growth in pension accounts” and “should definite(ly) be paying some form of taxation on earnings and ongoing growth”

Transfer balance caps introduced in 2017 mean that only $1.6-2.0m (depending on timing and subject to annual draw-down rules) can be held in a tax free pension account while the remainder has to be transferred to an accumulation account which is currently taxed at 15% and may soon be taxed at 30% on amounts over $3m.

Jane
June 27, 2025

Apart from mandatory SG, no one is forced to put anything into super. So isn't it up to each individual, not the government, to estimate their required illiquidity premium? As you have stated this number would be different for each person. And clearly a lot of people are very happy to shove their money into the current system with 15% tax rate.
Frankly regarding SG, the economic benefits of such a system have outweighed detriment to any individual. Savings that the government makes on age pension being the most obvious one, but also the stability of our financial markets and investment into productive assets. Should the government also calculate a premium on how each individual benefits by living in a (relatively) thriving economy?

John
June 27, 2025

The taxes on superannuation should not be seen as receiving a concession. Rather they should be seen as a bonus. If it wasn't for superannuation the majority of this money would not be invested in taxable assets. More likely spent on housing, holidays, new cars etc.

Dudley
June 27, 2025

"Rather they should be seen as a bonus.":

Economic fertiliser.

RichardL
June 27, 2025

Another in a long list of disingenuous articles on this and related topics, Tony! Not just from you, I hasten to add.

The wealthiest have their huge tax concessions because they have dialled UP the amount that they have put into super. They are so upset with the money being locked up and overtaxed that they fight to put in as much as possible! So, I suggest that your utility value is just plain wrong.

Furthermore, the point here is that the system is there for everyone because that's the simplest way to operate it, but it was never actually necessary to compensate the wealthy AT ALL for saving for retirement. So, any and all such compensation is a system cost that should be minimised.

Not that I expect much agreement here!

Tony Dillon
June 27, 2025

Hi Richard, I did say: “Note that this analysis is based on a specific discount rate curve for illiquidity, the rate and shape of which can vary depending on individual circumstances”.

And for the very wealthy, I agree, they want to lock their money up, and their personal discount rate would be zero, perhaps even negative, because their motives for super are not on a par with the general population. They are not using super to provide for retirement, they are using at as a tax-preferred haven for estate planning. And the Div 296 tax will deal with that, which is a good thing.

But those very large super funds are very much in the minority, and this article is not pitched at extreme scenarios. It’s all about pointing out that the TEIS benchmark is inappropriate in arriving at the $50 odd billion in concessions, given the unique access restrictions and compulsory nature of super. It is an inappropriate benchmark for average PAYG workers who are forced into locking their money away for up to decades when they have large mortgages and young families to support. Even those who voluntarily contribute to super to top up their retirement savings go into the system in good faith, but know they are tying their money up at a cost for the greater good, and they are prepared to forgo immediate consumption to achieve that.

That there is a liquidity cost for the vast majority of individuals is without doubt. And clearly, tax concessions assigned to them under the TEIS basis are overstated.

OldbutSane
June 27, 2025

This article gives little insight as to whether the $50b is in fact correct. The way I see it is that super has become a very effective tax minimisation strategy for too many people and that the rate of tax paid in this concessional environment is too low for those with larger balances. One can argue what that limit should be, but somewhere between the pension limit (from 1 July $2m) and $3m seems reasonable given that $2m will generate a minimum pension of $100,000 tax-free at age 65, which is about what the average worker gets before tax! And you will also probably get the CHCC too.

Also, GeorgeB

1 Paying taxes does not "entitle" you to a pension, the age pension is not a contributory system like eg UK, and pensions in Australia have always been means tested (arguably pretty lightly here as a couple can have over $1m in assets, plus a house, and still get some pension).

2 Private health insurance does not mean that you are not getting some benefit from the taxes you pay - you at least get the health insurance rebate. Medicare contributions to medical expenses, both in and out of hospital and emergency treatment at public hospitals.

3. Many built up significant super balances from pre-tax super using salary sacrifice contributions especially those who were old enough to also take transition to retirement pensions (when they were untaxed).

Dudley
June 26, 2025

"If government is going to motivate people to save for retirement, it must be prepared to offer meaningful incentives to individuals for giving up access to large sums of money for many years.":

Most have more immediate applications for cash; one being home ownership which brings more immediate benefits.

Saving for minimum equity or full equity have their own liquidity discount rates superimposed on the retirement liquidity discount rate.

HandyAndy
June 26, 2025

Also ... doesn't the government effectively recoup some of the"concessions" from the acounts of those who die with funds still in super? I'm not sure if this tax collection is accounted for in the super tax concessions $50 billion annual figure.

KIm
June 26, 2025

Of course, Treasury omits the fact that Super savers don't cost the Government money in the form of pensions.

Ross
June 26, 2025

Is there not also an opportunity cost discount eg. money locked up in a SF could have also been used to reduce the loan amount of a mortgage or other loan which has a compounding affect as a mortgage offset account? Perhaps this is just part of the liquidity discount

Terri Bradford
June 26, 2025

Exactly! Exactly! Exactly! Has been my point always - the superannuation rate of 15% is NOT a concession. It is part of the carrot & stick approach adopted by Government when superannuation was introduced as a retirement savings vehicle. Great article Tony, thank you.

Philip
June 26, 2025

It is not just the liquidity lockup that is negative - in super you can’t borrow, you are restricted as to the type of assets you can invest in - administration is excessive (audits etc) and ultimately you are forced to withdraw it via the pension obligations

Greg
June 26, 2025

A really refreshing way of looking at the "cost" assertion for super concessions.

And, I support the proposition "if Treasury is going to introduce measures to help sway the debate, surely it has a duty to estimate those measures as accurately as possible". This proposition could usefully be applied to political claims in general.

Stuart
June 26, 2025

It seems that the effect of the upfront contributions tax is being ignored. The effect of that is dramatic.

Philip
June 26, 2025

Very good point!!!

CC
June 26, 2025

And there is already the Div 293 tax surcharge ( extra 15 %, total 30% ) for all contributions for higher income earners ( over $250k per annum )

Jim Bonham
June 26, 2025

Tony, thanks for this article. It is really refreshing to see this fundamental point argued out in some detail.

Pete
June 26, 2025

I get the impression that authors of these papers on the cost of tax concessions start from the premise that the government is entitled to 100% of an individual’s earnings. Anything they allow us to keep is then a tax concession.

James#
June 26, 2025

"It quotes a total super tax concessions figure in the vicinity of $50 billion annually, a misleading figure that the proposed new super tax relies heavily upon for justification."

And that's exactly why Chalmers won't be remotely interested in considering such things as liquidity discounting (not that he'd understand it, as an economist he is not)! As the old adage goes: "never spoil a good story with the facts"

Franco
June 26, 2025

Even more crazy, a retired couple have $3million each in super at 5% and investments earning about $60000 a year outside super. They receive $360,000 per year tax free !! Is that enough for a comfortable retirement ?
oops ,sorry that doesnt fit in with the Firstlink Responders

Dudley
June 26, 2025

"retired couple have $3million each in super at 5% and investments earning about $60000 a year outside super. They receive $360,000 per year tax free":

After the inflation 'stealth tax' they receive:
= ((1 + 5%) / (1 + 3%) - 1) * (2 * 3000000)
= $116,504.85
Less than two after tax average full-time wages:
= 2 * 79076
= $158,144

GeorgeB
June 26, 2025

Point 1. Super is no longer tax free in retirement - anyone with more that the transfer balance cap ($1.6-2.0m depending on timing and subject to annual draw-down rules) must transfer the rest of their super balance to an accumulation account which is currently taxed at 15% and may soon be taxed at 30% on amounts over $3m.
Point.2. Significant tax was paid to get $6m into super – large balances are generally built up with large after tax contributions already taxed at up to 50% or more depending on timing plus concessional contributions taxed at 15-30% again depending on timing.
Point 3. The contributions were locked up for 40 years or more – to encourage contributions when they were not compulsory there was an explicit condition/promise that super would be entirely tax free in retirement, this being the carrot that was used to encourage contributions and delay consumption.
Point 4. The retired couple are unlikely to qualify for the aged pension or other handouts that their lifetime taxes paid for because they are fully self-funded. They are also likely to have private health insurance so will not benefit from the public health system that their lifetime taxes paid for.

Franco
June 26, 2025

Hi Dudley and George , i was expecting those sort of comments so lets assume growth in ivestments of 5 to 6 percent per annum. Dudley really ! they are left with $158,000 ! Only half of the $360,000. You are good with YOUR calculations.
And your average full time wages before tax are $102000 but the median is $88000 .
So with growth factored in and extra taxes (yes George a lttle extra for having over $2million and the going over $3million ) they may only clear aroud $300000+per year. How will they survive.
Yes they paid more tax in their lifetime but much less if it wasnt in superannuation. Non concessional not taxed going in and if it was taxed at 50% why put into super in the first place,
As they say about vested interests and complaining wealthy boomers.

Dudley
June 27, 2025

"left with $158,000 ! Only half of the $360,000":
They can reinvest $202,000 to make good that capital loss due to inflation 'stealth tax'.
A worker whose wage increases with inflation does not have capital loss due to inflation.

GeorgeB
June 27, 2025

"Non concessional not taxed going in"

Non concessional contributions are not taxed going in because they have already been taxed as income, meaning (for higher income earners) that about $1 income tax was paid for every $1 contributed.

"if it was taxed at 50% why put into super in the first place"

Because this is the reality of being a high income earner, ie.you pay $1 tax for every $1 you want to spend or save, so its not just on savings going into super but on savings outside super and on all consumption. Of course there was also the promise that if you waited another 30 or 40 years your super would be tax free in retirement.

The reward for those lifelong taxes is that you get to be a fully funded retiree meaning that you are locked out of all govt handouts that the lifelong taxes paid for.

Franco
June 27, 2025

Firstly George , non concessional contibutions are very often after a CG event where the max tax rate is less than 25% of the gain. You seen stuck on how much tax you have paid and not getting it back. Paying no tax on Super after turning 60 and paying 15% in super does not seem that bad. Considering the tax on $250000 is in total 33% and thats if you dont negative gear into investments so that you can then pay max 25% of CG.
Dudley you are obsessed with inflation as a tax but continue to ignore the growth of Super which i believe has been averaging about 8% over a long period. That should cover your inflation of average 2.4%. Im also intrigued by your maths, couldnt you have gone
8% growth on $6mill( 480K)- 5% drawdown(300K) -3% inflation(180K) so the couple still have about $6 mill
Yes the $6mill is not worth as much due to inflation but they have at least $240K +to live on.
( possibly some other tax, lets say $60K so they are left with $240K + $60K outside super= $300K)

GeorgeB
June 27, 2025

“non-concessional contributions are very often after a CG event where the max tax rate is less than 25% of the gain”
Non concessional contributions are after tax contributions and the tax paid depends on the source of the funds. If the source of funds are entirely from personal income taxed at the highest marginal rates then about $1 income tax is paid for every $1 contributed (in our SMSF more than 2/3 of the contributions were after tax).

“Paying no tax on Super after turning 60 and paying 15% in super does not seem that bad.”
After 2017 paying no tax on Super after turning 60 or retiring will only apply if your super balance remains below the relevant TBC , beyond that you will pay 15% and will likely pay an additional 15% on any balance above $3m.

“You seem stuck on how much tax you have paid and not getting it back.”
I have long ago stopped worrying about only getting to keep half of my hard earned and not getting anything in return. However it’s a matter of contention whether the changes to super that occurred in 2017 and the further changes that are now being considered are reasonable in the context in which the contributions were made.

Harry
June 27, 2025

Franco, can you explain how you believe a couple earning $60k outside super pay no tax.

 

Leave a Comment:

RELATED ARTICLES

7 examples of how the new super tax will be calculated

Did retirees lose out when they accepted defined benefit schemes?

How to prevent excessive superannuation balances

banner

Most viewed in recent weeks

Australian house prices close in on world record

Sydney is set to become the world’s most expensive city for housing over the next 12 months, a new report shows. Our other major cities aren’t far behind unless there are major changes to improve housing affordability.

The case for the $3 million super tax

The Government's proposed tax has copped a lot of flack though I think it's a reasonable approach to improve the long-term sustainability of superannuation and the retirement income system. Here’s why.

7 examples of how the new super tax will be calculated

You've no doubt heard about Division 296. These case studies show what people at various levels above the $3 million threshold might need to pay the ATO, with examples ranging from under $500 to more than $35,000.

The revolt against Baby Boomer wealth

The $3m super tax could be put down to the Government needing money and the wealthy being easy targets. It’s deeper than that though and this looks at the factors behind the policy and why more taxes on the wealthy are coming.

Meg on SMSFs: Withdrawing assets ahead of the $3m super tax

The super tax has caused an almighty scuffle, but for SMSFs impacted by the proposed tax, a big question remains: what should they do now? Here are ideas for those wanting to withdraw money from their SMSF.

The super tax and the defined benefits scandal

Australia's superannuation inequities date back to poor decisions made by Parliament two decades ago. If super for the wealthy needs resetting, so too does the defined benefits schemes for our public servants.

Latest Updates

Planning

Will young Australians be better off than their parents?

For much of Australia’s history, each new generation has been better off than the last: better jobs and incomes as well as improved living standards. A new report assesses whether this time may be different.

Superannuation

The rubbery numbers behind super tax concessions

In selling the super tax, Labor has repeated Treasury claims of there being $50 billion in super tax concessions annually, mostly flowing to high-income earners. This figure is vastly overstated.

Investment strategies

A steady road to getting rich

The latest lists of Australia’s wealthiest individuals show that while overall wealth has continued to rise, gains by individuals haven't been uniform. Many might have been better off adopting a simpler investment strategy.

Economy

Would a corporate tax cut boost productivity in Australia?

As inflation eases, the Albanese government is switching its focus to lifting Australia’s sluggish productivity. Can corporate tax cuts reboot growth - or are we chasing a theory that doesn’t quite work here?

Are V-shaped market recoveries becoming more frequent?

April’s sharp rebound may feel familiar, but are V-shaped recoveries really more common in the post-COVID world? A look at market history suggests otherwise and hints that a common bias might be skewing perceptions.

Investment strategies

Asset allocation in a world of riskier developed markets

Old distinctions between developed and emerging market bonds no longer hold true. At a time where true diversification matters more than ever, this has big ramifications for the way that portfolios should be constructed.

Investment strategies

Top 5 investment reads

As the July school holiday break nears, here are some investment classics to put onto your reading list. The books offer lessons in investment strategy, financial disasters, and mergers and acquisitions.

Sponsors

Alliances

© 2025 Morningstar, Inc. All rights reserved.

Disclaimer
The data, research and opinions provided here are for information purposes; are not an offer to buy or sell a security; and are not warranted to be correct, complete or accurate. Morningstar, its affiliates, and third-party content providers are not responsible for any investment decisions, damages or losses resulting from, or related to, the data and analyses or their use. To the extent any content is general advice, it has been prepared for clients of Morningstar Australasia Pty Ltd (ABN: 95 090 665 544, AFSL: 240892), without reference to your financial objectives, situation or needs. For more information refer to our Financial Services Guide. You should consider the advice in light of these matters and if applicable, the relevant Product Disclosure Statement before making any decision to invest. Past performance does not necessarily indicate a financial product’s future performance. To obtain advice tailored to your situation, contact a professional financial adviser. Articles are current as at date of publication.
This website contains information and opinions provided by third parties. Inclusion of this information does not necessarily represent Morningstar’s positions, strategies or opinions and should not be considered an endorsement by Morningstar.

OSZAR »